Political economy

Earlier, William Stanley Jevons, a proponent of mathematical methods applied to the subject, advocated economics for brevity and with the hope of the term becoming "the recognised name of a science".

Political economy was thus meant to express the laws of production of wealth at the state level, quite like economics concerns putting home to order.

Other contemporary scholars attribute the roots of this study to the 13th Century Tunisian Arab Historian and Sociologist, Ibn Khaldun, for his work on making the distinction between "profit" and "sustenance", in modern political economy terms, surplus and that required for the reproduction of classes respectively.

In Al-Muqaddimah Khaldun states, "Civilization and its well-being, as well as business prosperity, depend on productivity and people's efforts in all directions in their own interest and profit" – seen as a modern precursor to Classical Economic thought.

Both approaches model voters, politicians and bureaucrats as behaving in mainly self-interested ways, in contrast to a view, ascribed to earlier mainstream economists, of government officials trying to maximize individual utilities from some kind of social welfare function.

[21] Other "traditional" topics include analysis of such public policy issues as economic regulation,[22] monopoly, rent-seeking, market protection,[23] institutional corruption[24] and distributional politics.

[30] From the mid-1990s, the field has expanded, in part aided by new cross-national data sets allowing tests of hypotheses on comparative economic systems and institutions.

Jean-Jacques Rousseau , Discours sur l'oeconomie politique , 1758
Robert Keohane , international relations theorist
Susan Strange , international relations scholar