Welfare cost of business cycles

Empirical methods Prescriptive and policy In macroeconomics, the cost of business cycles is the decrease in social welfare, if any, caused by business cycle fluctuations.

Nobel economist Robert Lucas proposed measuring the cost of business cycles as the percentage increase in consumption that would be necessary to make a representative consumer indifferent between a smooth, non-fluctuating, consumption trend and one that is subject to business cycles.

Under the assumptions that business cycles represent random shocks around a trend growth path, Robert Lucas argued that the cost of business cycles is extremely small,[1][2] and as a result the focus of both academic economists and policy makers on economic stabilization policy rather than on long term growth has been misplaced.

[3][4] Lucas himself, after calculating this cost back in 1987, reoriented his own macroeconomic research program away from the study of short run fluctuations.

In particular, Keynesian economists typically argue that business cycles should not be understood as fluctuations above and below a trend.

Instead, they argue that booms are times when the economy is near its potential output trend, and that recessions are times when the economy is substantially below trend, so that there is a large output gap.

One way to calculate how costly this greater volatility is in terms of individual (or, under some restrictive conditions, social) welfare is to ask what percentage of her annual average consumption would an individual be willing to sacrifice in order to eliminate this volatility entirely.

Another way to express this is by asking how much an individual with a smooth consumption path would have to be compensated in terms of average consumption in order to accept the volatile path instead of the one without the volatility.

The resulting amount of compensation, expressed as a percentage of average annual consumption, is the cost of the fluctuations calculated by Lucas.

It is a function of people's degree of risk aversion and of the magnitude of the fluctuations which are to be eliminated, as measured by the standard deviation of the natural log of consumption.

[6] Robert Lucas' baseline formula for the welfare cost of business cycles is given by (see mathematical derivation below): where

; although it should be theoretically possible, many controversies in economics revolve around the precise and appropriate measurement of this parameter.

In this case the welfare cost of fluctuations is In other words, eliminating all the fluctuations from a person's consumption path (i.e., eliminating the business cycle entirely) is worth only 1/20 of 1 percent of average annual consumption.

For example, an individual who consumes $50,000 worth of goods a year on average would be willing to pay only $25 to eliminate consumption fluctuations.

The implication is that, if the calculation is correct and appropriate, the ups and downs of the business cycles, the recessions and the booms, hardly matter for individual and possibly social welfare.

It is the long run trend of economic growth that is crucial.

is at the upper range of estimates found in literature, around 4, then or 1/5 of 1 percent.

An individual with average consumption of $50,000 would be willing to pay $100 to eliminate fluctuations.

This is still a very small amount compared to the implications of long run growth on income.

One way to get an upper bound on the degree of risk aversion is to use the Ramsey model of intertemporal savings and consumption.

is generally estimated to be around 5% (.05) and the annual growth rate of consumption is about 2% (.02).

This implies that the highest possible degree of risk aversion is which in turn, combined with estimates given above, yields a cost of fluctuations as which is still extremely small (13% of 1%).

Lucas sets up an infinitely lived representative agent model where total lifetime utility (

is the growth rate of consumption (neither of these parameters turns out to matter for costs of fluctuations in the baseline model, so they can be normalized to 1 and 0 respectively).

In other words, with log utility the cost of fluctuations is equal to one half the variance of the natural logarithm of consumption.

[6] An alternative, more accurate solution gives losses that are somewhat larger, especially when volatility is large.

) and in fact, possibly to Lucas' entire approach is the so-called equity premium puzzle, first observed by Mehra and Prescott in 1985.

In a survey of the implications of the equity premium, Simon Grant and John Quiggin note that 'A high cost of risk means that recessions are extremely destructive'.

[9] Justin Wolfers has shown that macroeconomic volatility reduces subjective wellbeing; the effects are somewhat larger than expected under the Lucas approach.

According to Wolfers, 'eliminating unemployment volatility would raise well-being by an amount roughly equal to that from lowering the average level of unemployment by a quarter of a percentage point'.

Compensating an individual for volatility in consumption (click to enlarge)