Taxation in the Ottoman Empire

Taxation in the Ottoman Empire changed drastically over time, and was a complex patchwork of different taxes, exemptions, and local customs.

[1] For instance, at the conquest of Belgrade, the Sultan instructed an official to gather information on the pre-conquest tax system, which would be replicated post-conquest.

[13] There was a special vlach tax, rusum-e eflak: one sheep and one lamb from each household on St Georges day each year.

[16] Sometimes, the "taxation" of churches by the Ottoman authorities could be shockingly direct: in 1603 Franciscan friars in Bosnia were imprisoned until they paid an arbitrary fee of 3000 aspers for permission to stay in their monasteries.

[19] The demand for taxes was higher during times of war; these factors together could provoke a vicious circle of taxation and rebellion[20] – in 1585, 2000 villagers near Debar revolted over an increase in cizye.

[22] In 17th–18th century, changes in warfare (favouring professional infantry over feudal cavalry) put more emphasis on taxes rather than on military duties; hence, when timars fell vacant they were taken over by the state and converted into tax-farms and private estates.

[24] There was a shift towards fully owned hereditary estates rather than feudal lords; ciftlik were preferred to timar, because tenants had fewer rights – hence more cash could be extracted from them.

[25] The Hatt-ı Şerif of Gülhane declared the equality of different ethnic and religious groups – abolishing the Kanun-i Raya – and reformed taxes.

[citation needed] In 1839, Sultan Abdülmecid I pushed a set of major new reforms to the tax system, including the abolition of tax-farming.

[30][31] The restructuring of the tax system was a central goal of the Tanzimat ("ordering") reforms, even though practical implementation remained limited.

Faced with the economic, military, and technological superiority of the Western European powers and Russia, the Sublime Porte aimed to centralize and strengthen the administration, while granting formal legal equality and self-administration rights to the members of the Millet confessional communities.

[33] Despite the efforts at reform, however, increases in tax revenue did not match the growing expenditure, so that the government more and more had to rely on foreign loans.

For instance, Armenians in the Anatolian provinces traditionally paid protection taxes to local notables and tribesmen, most of them Kurds.

A treaty from 1536, granting concessions to the French across the whole of the Ottoman Empire
A receipt for cizye (poll-tax) paid by the village of Chokmanovo .